A task force under the government-appointed Commission on Poverty met on
Monday to draw up the first official poverty line for Hong Kong. According to
recent media reports, the group is favour of a definition of poverty as
measured with the common method used by the OECD and the EU and the Hong Kong
government was also inclined to adopting this model.
While local pressure groups and some respectable academics have long
been clamouring for the establishment of an official poverty line for the city,
there seems to be some popular illusion that such a threshold can reflect how
many people in our society are poor and how many are not or whether the
livelihood of residents has improved or worsened over time. This is perhaps because the phrase “poverty line”
itself is a misleading term. Even some members of the Commission reportedly
expressed surprise when they heard that the benchmark under discussion would
not measure people’s material wealth and urged the government to “clarify” what
it meant. (Note 1)
If people under the poverty line are poor and those above it are not,
then the poverty rate should be higher in poor societies and vice versa,
shouldn’t it? Perfectly logical in common sense. But this is not the case. In
2010, the poverty rate of Germany, which was envied by its European neighbours
for its relative economic strength in the aftermath of the global financial
crisis, was higher than that of the struggling Hungary by two percentage
points, despite the per capita GDP of the former outstripped the latter by more
than 80%, for example. (Notes 2 and 3)
Why does the poverty rate not tell how rich or how poor a society is?
Take a quick look at how the OECD/EU poverty rate is calculated and one can immediately
realise where the problem lies. The mathematical
formula is simple – the population under the poverty line is those whose
household incomes fall below a certain percentage, usually 40%, 50% or 60%, of
the median of the society.
Instead of indicating the income levels of the general population or of
the economically worse off group, this measurement of relative poverty (as
opposed to absolute poverty) is rather an outcome of the distribution of
income.
Suppose 100 households lived in Town X with an income distribution like
this in a given year:
Income ($)
|
Number of households
|
20
|
4
|
30
|
6
|
40
|
10
|
50
|
22
|
60
|
20
|
70
|
12
|
80
|
10
|
90
|
8
|
100
|
6
|
110
|
2
|
Total
|
100
|
The median household income is $60. If the poverty line is drawn at 50%
of that, then 10% of all households will fall below the threshold. (For the
sake of simplicity the difference in the numbers of people in households is
ignored here.)
Now in the following year, 20 households immigrated to Town X, most of
them with incomes above the median level. Some high earners who had been living
here also saw their incomes increase. On the other hand, those living on the
lowest end of the breadline made even less money this year, with some even
losing their jobs and left with no income.
Income ($)
|
Number of households
|
0
|
2
|
10
|
2
|
20
|
2
|
30
|
4
|
40
|
10
|
50
|
26
|
60
|
22
|
70
|
14
|
80
|
12
|
90
|
12
|
100
|
8
|
110
|
4
|
120
|
2
|
Total
|
120
|
The
median household income remained at $60. However, the official poverty rate
with the above definition would drop to 8.3%. This is despite the fact that the
poor in Town X have actually become poorer. (An interactive graphical
illustration of how changes in people’s incomes move the poverty rate can be
found at http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/magazine/8177864.stm.)
Another reason why this way to define poverty is misleading is, as
researchers in the academia have pointed
out and at least one member of the Commission has raised in the media, that
income is the sole measurement while assets are not taken into account. Some
retirees may have no income at all yet enjoy a well-off material life on their
accumulated wealth while some young people may earn wages which do not look but
cannot afford to live on their own. As the population of Hong Kong is ageing,
the age structure is expected to have an effect on the movement of such an
official poverty line.
The OECD/EU model of poverty measurement
has also been criticised for setting an arbitrary standard. Why should the
percentage be set at 40% but not 50%, or 50% but not 60%? However an advocate
explains the percentage he or she goes for, it is after all a subjective line.
Indeed where the line should be drawn has become a centre of debate in the
current discussion in Hong Kong, whereas the basic concept of drawing a line in
this way seems to have become the general consensus between Commission and the
administration. There have been voices raising concern that the government may
adopt a lower threshold to make the population under the poverty line look
smaller. These are merely manipulation of numbers and I am not going into this
argument of what percentage is the best for I reckon that it is unrealistic to
look for a benchmark free of subjectivity and biases. In fact the
OECD website presents poverty data measured with three commonly used percentages.
(Note 4) It appears that Commission members and many vocal advocates for this
official poverty line in Hong Kong prefer the use of one single line to avoid
complexity.
What
I would like to caution against is the type of arguments like “The line should
be set at 40% because Hong Kong is an affluent society” or “The line should be
set at 60% because the cost of living in Hong Kong is so high”. If these logics
applied, then the official poverty line could be moved as our GDP or inflation
rate moved every year, which would effectively make the line meaningless. Although the setting of the line is
inevitably a political process, the exercise to measure poverty statistically should
not be used as a political tool to reaffirm existing views on poverty. Instead,
it should be a tool with a purpose to help make policies on poverty
alleviation.
Because it is convenient, such a
definition of poverty has been commonly used in many countries despite its
questionability as a poverty indicator. In recent decades the study of
inequality in developed countries has been moving toward a more comprehensive
view, such as developing more encompassing concepts like deprivation social
exclusion, standard of living and quality of life, rather than drawing a simple
line on the income curve. The Hong Kong government is aware of these new options
but has chosen to go for the old, established, convenient, one-dimensional
measurement and NGOs speaking on the issue appear to be happy about that.
In spite of these limitations of
the OECD/EU model of the poverty line, I would not say it is totally useless
for Hong Kong. As Commission member and Oxfam Hong Kong director-general Mr. Stephen
Fisher has pointed out, one major function of an official poverty line is to
assess the effectiveness of public policies on poverty alleviation. (Note 5)
Professor CK Law wrote a newspaper article last year which gave a clear
elaboration on how it could be done and readers who are interested can refer
it. (Note 6) However, for the sake of
comprehensiveness and to point out some confusion in recent media reports
please bear with me for being a bit repetitive here.
Take a glance at the OECD
poverty statistical table and one can spot there are two sets of poverty rates,
“poverty rates before taxes and transfers” and “poverty rates after taxes and
transfers”. (Note 4) By comparing the two sets of data, we can find out to what
extent an economy’s taxation and welfare policies have changed income
distribution. Certainly a general
subtraction does not tell us which policy is working for the poor and which is
not and why, but nonetheless it serves as a reference of how effective
government intervention is. More detailed analyses of sub-groups can be
conducted with demographic data.
An understanding of this use of the official poverty line (despite one
does not have to agree with it) is significant in the whole discussion of how
the line(s) should be drawn and, in my humble opinion, why we hold such a discussion
at all. After all, why does a poverty line has to be “official”? The Oxfam can draw
its own line and so can the Hong Kong Council of Social Service. The local
academia is not short of studies in poverty and there is a variety of
measurements available to choose from in literature. (Note 7) If the only reasons
for setting a poverty line are to keep records and conduct analyses, which
carry importance in their own rights, then we can be happy without an official
definition, which can be authoritarian. The most important point of making an
official line is to for policymaking purposes.
Recognising this reason for making an official poverty line and the
rationale behind having a “poverty rate before taxes
and transfers” and a “poverty rate after taxes and transfers” should be able to
alert us not to confuse the two rates. I found some recent news reports intriguing
and I do not know if it were the Commission members and pressure group
representatives being interviewed or the journalists who had mixed up the
concepts (Hopefully not the Commission members because they are the ones
responsible for the task). Some recent reports warned against “the inclusion of
welfare in the calculation of the poverty line” by the government (e.g. Notes 5
and 8). I myself was stunned when I first came across the headlines and I am
afraid most readers might be misled that welfare would be included in the
calculation of the commonly understood single poverty line unless they take the
time and effort to read some original documents. If it were the case that government
welfare was included in THE poverty line which people talk about, then it would
depict an extremely unrealistic picture of poverty in Hong Kong. I appreciate the fact that there are still a
wide range of possibilities of how to measure the “poverty rate after taxes and
transfers” and I agree that some of the concerns raised such as the inclusion
of universal services like nine-year free education might come up with the
false picture of “zero poverty” is valid in this sense. However, distinguishing
the two lines and conveying the real purpose of setting an official poverty
line to the public is still important.
Notes
- 1. The Hong Kong Economic Journal, Jan 29, 2013, ‘貧窮線不代表窮 議員促釐清作用’
- 2. http://www.indexmundi.com/map/?v=69&r=eu&l=en
- 3. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_OFFPUB/KS-SF-11-064/EN/KS-SF-11-064-EN.PDF
- 4. (http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DatasetCode=POVERTY)
- 5. The Hong Kong Economic Journal, Jan 28, 2013, ‘余志穩:訂貧窮線毋須一年 倡入息中位一半劃線 憂政府降指標當滅貧’
- 6. Mingpao, Sept 30, ‘貧窮線用來做甚麼?’
- 7. See for example a brief review by Professor Chou Kee-lee in Mingpao, Dec 17, 2012, ‘如何訂定本港的貧窮線? ‘
- 8. The Apple Daily, Jan 29, 2013, ‘福利當收入 貧窮線恐變粉飾數字’
No comments:
Post a Comment